In many ways, our class has been an exploration of the
failures of regulation in the wine industry.
Our first guest from a winery, Caroline Wente, discussed her frustration
with the outsized power of distributors largely attributable to their favorable
regulatory position. Tracy Genesen
litigated a case before the United States Supreme Court successfully loosening
the states’ vice grip on out-of-state imports. Ann Baum contributed a great blog post called "Canned Wine -- More Obscure Regulation Hampering the Industry."
All agree that without the labyrinthine framework of state, federal, and Constitutional law to deal with, wine would ship more freely to more people, and producers and consumers would be better off. So why do we regulate wine?
All agree that without the labyrinthine framework of state, federal, and Constitutional law to deal with, wine would ship more freely to more people, and producers and consumers would be better off. So why do we regulate wine?
James Thornton, in American
Wine Economics, sets forth an economic and public interest theory as to why
we regulate wine.
From an economic perspective, Thornton raises three
justifications for government interference with the wine market. First, wine creates externalities. A consumer who enjoys a bottle of wine at a
restaurant then causes an accident while driving home due to her impairment
does not internalize the cost of her actions absent perfect insurance markets. She pays for the price of the bottle, but not
for the medical costs and repairs associated with the accident. Extrapolating from this example, these
externalities indicate that too much wine would be produced and consumed in the
United States without regulation. Tools
like taxes and regulatory restrictions allow the government to bring consumption
back in line with the socially optimal level. This is illustrated by the graph
below where the PMB line indicates demand with externalities, and the SMB line
indicates demand with the costs of such externalities internalized by the
consumer. The dead weight welfare loss
created by the difference between these two lines is indicated as well. Regulation, when done correctly, can bring
these two curves closer together, and bring society to a more optimal place.
Second, to make the rational choices that lead to efficient
markets, consumers need cheap information.
If they do not have access to complete information or are not able to
understand it, they will make irrational choices. For example, if people are unaware of the
health benefits of drinking wine in moderation, they may abstain, which would
lead to higher healthcare costs. The
government can intervene by investing in research and publishing information to
educate consumers.
Finally, Thornton points to the antitrust case for wine
regulation. Absent interference,
producers, distributors and retailers may engage in anticompetitive behavior
and gain damaging market power.
Our current system of regulation may succeed on the first and
second poinst but fails on the third.
Regulations and taxes certainly increase the cost to the
consumer of drinking wine. Quantifying
whether the level of cost increase is in keeping with the actual externalities
associated with drinking wine is challenging, but it is likely in the right
direction.
On the information production front, government regulations
do require wine manufacturers to state the risks of drinking while pregnant and
of operating heavy machinery while inebriated.
There is also much public investment in consumer education about the
dangers of drinking and driving. The
public media takes care of informing readers about new studies about the health
benefits of wine in moderation.
Finally, the system utterly fails on the antitrust
front. The wine wholesaler market is
dominated by Southern Glazer’s, and revenues at the top three wholesalers equal
half the total value of the U.S. wine market.[1] The market power effects of this structure
are evident at every tier of the United States system. However, contrary to the tone of our class
previously, this may call more government involvement, not less, in the form of
antitrust action.
[1] https://www.forbes.com/sites/thomaspellechia/2017/09/20/revenues-at-three-wine-distributors-tally-almost-half-of-the-u-s-wine-market-value/#37b43113299f
No comments:
Post a Comment